So now let's talk about the terms for the trade. What is the correct price to set for the exchange? So first off, for trade to be beneficial to both trading partners, the price of the trade must lie between their opportunity costs. That is the only way that the trade will be beneficial. Here I've got the graphs of your and your friends' parties with the hunch punch and the pizza rolls, and we've got the opportunity cost that we had solved for in a previous video. Right? We knew who had the comparative advantage in each one, right? Whoever has the lower opportunity cost, but now how do we say what the trade should be, right? Should we trade at 1 hunch punch for 1 pizza roll? Is that fair? 2 hunch punches for 1 pizza roll, 3 hunch punches for 1 pizza roll. Where is the correct amount of the trade? Okay, so what's going to happen is we're going to have a range that is okay for the trade. Anywhere within this range, the trade will be beneficial to both. Where we set ourselves in this range comes down to some other factors, but first let's set what the range would be. So remember, it has to lie between the opportunity costs. So the price of the trade in this situation has to lie between 1 hunch punch and 2 hunch punches. Right? Let's say the price of the trade was 2 hunch punches for 1 pizza roll. Why would you even want to trade, right? You can already do that yourself. You would need to be getting something a little better than 2 hunch punches for 1, to even consider it. Right? You'd want to be getting 1.5 or something like that or even 1 if you could, but if you wanted 1 hunch punch for one pizza roll, your friend would say, hey, that's not fair. I could do that myself. Right? My opportunity cost is 1 hunch punch. So for it to be beneficial to both, it's got to lie somewhere in between those two numbers. So it would have to be something like 1.5 like we had in our previous example or 1.2 or 1.8, right? It could be anywhere in this range and it would be beneficial to both parties. It's just where do we end up. So let's see the same thing with the price of the trade for hunch punch and we're saying how many pizza rolls for 1 hunch punch. Well in this situation, it would have to lie between half a pizza roll per hunch punch and 1 pizza roll per hunch punch, right? Same logic here. You wouldn't want to make the trade unless it was in between that range or both people wouldn't want to make the trade, right? So why was the trade set to 1.5 hunch punches per pizza roll before? Why did that number come up? Well first off it was right in the middle, right? So that was one reason it could have ended up thicker, but there are other factors that can come into play. Right? The supply and demand of pizza rolls and hunch punch. What if pizza rolls are really rare and hunch punch is just everywhere? You can just get hunch punch at any old 711. The value of a hunch punch isn't as great, right, so that could affect where the price of the trade would be. How about negotiating power? Just one person's a better negotiator, they might get a trade better in their favor, and the last thing here, equity. They could try and make an equitable trade where everybody is better off. Set. Alright. Let's move on.
- 0. Basic Principles of Economics1h 5m
- Introduction to Economics3m
- People Are Rational2m
- People Respond to Incentives1m
- Scarcity and Choice2m
- Marginal Analysis9m
- Allocative Efficiency, Productive Efficiency, and Equality7m
- Positive and Normative Analysis7m
- Microeconomics vs. Macroeconomics2m
- Factors of Production5m
- Circular Flow Diagram5m
- Graphing Review10m
- Percentage and Decimal Review4m
- Fractions Review2m
- 1. Reading and Understanding Graphs59m
- 2. Introductory Economic Models1h 10m
- 3. The Market Forces of Supply and Demand2h 26m
- Competitive Markets10m
- The Demand Curve13m
- Shifts in the Demand Curve24m
- Movement Along a Demand Curve5m
- The Supply Curve9m
- Shifts in the Supply Curve22m
- Movement Along a Supply Curve3m
- Market Equilibrium8m
- Using the Supply and Demand Curves to Find Equilibrium3m
- Effects of Surplus3m
- Effects of Shortage2m
- Supply and Demand: Quantitative Analysis40m
- 4. Elasticity2h 16m
- Percentage Change and Price Elasticity of Demand10m
- Elasticity and the Midpoint Method20m
- Price Elasticity of Demand on a Graph11m
- Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand6m
- Total Revenue Test13m
- Total Revenue Along a Linear Demand Curve14m
- Income Elasticity of Demand23m
- Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand11m
- Price Elasticity of Supply12m
- Price Elasticity of Supply on a Graph3m
- Elasticity Summary9m
- 5. Consumer and Producer Surplus; Price Ceilings and Floors3h 45m
- Consumer Surplus and Willingness to Pay38m
- Producer Surplus and Willingness to Sell26m
- Economic Surplus and Efficiency18m
- Quantitative Analysis of Consumer and Producer Surplus at Equilibrium28m
- Price Ceilings, Price Floors, and Black Markets38m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Price Floors: Finding Points20m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Price Floors: Finding Areas54m
- 6. Introduction to Taxes and Subsidies1h 46m
- 7. Externalities1h 12m
- 8. The Types of Goods1h 13m
- 9. International Trade1h 16m
- 10. The Costs of Production2h 35m
- 11. Perfect Competition2h 23m
- Introduction to the Four Market Models2m
- Characteristics of Perfect Competition6m
- Revenue in Perfect Competition14m
- Perfect Competition Profit on the Graph20m
- Short Run Shutdown Decision33m
- Long Run Entry and Exit Decision18m
- Individual Supply Curve in the Short Run and Long Run6m
- Market Supply Curve in the Short Run and Long Run9m
- Long Run Equilibrium12m
- Perfect Competition and Efficiency15m
- Four Market Model Summary: Perfect Competition5m
- 12. Monopoly2h 13m
- Characteristics of Monopoly21m
- Monopoly Revenue12m
- Monopoly Profit on the Graph16m
- Monopoly Efficiency and Deadweight Loss20m
- Price Discrimination22m
- Antitrust Laws and Government Regulation of Monopolies11m
- Mergers and the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI)17m
- Four Firm Concentration Ratio6m
- Four Market Model Summary: Monopoly4m
- 13. Monopolistic Competition1h 9m
- 14. Oligopoly1h 26m
- 15. Markets for the Factors of Production1h 33m
- The Production Function and Marginal Revenue Product16m
- Demand for Labor in Perfect Competition7m
- Shifts in Labor Demand13m
- Supply of Labor in Perfect Competition7m
- Shifts in Labor Supply5m
- Differences in Wages6m
- Discrimination6m
- Other Factors of Production: Land and Capital5m
- Unions6m
- Monopsony11m
- Bilateral Monopoly5m
- 16. Income Inequality and Poverty35m
- 17. Asymmetric Information, Voting, and Public Choice39m
- 18. Consumer Choice and Behavioral Economics1h 16m
PPF - The Price of the Trade - Online Tutor, Practice Problems & Exam Prep
For trade to be mutually beneficial, the price must fall between the opportunity costs of the trading partners. This range ensures that both parties gain from the exchange. For example, if the opportunity cost of 1 pizza roll is 1 to 2 hunch punches, a fair trade price could be 1.5 hunch punches per pizza roll. Factors like supply and demand, negotiating power, and equity can influence the final trade price. Understanding these concepts is crucial for grasping market dynamics and achieving an efficient market outcome.
Now that we have decided to trade, how do we set the correct amounts to trade? Let's make a deal!
The Price of the Trade
Video transcript
Here’s what students ask on this topic:
What is the Production Possibility Frontier (PPF) and how does it relate to opportunity cost?
The Production Possibility Frontier (PPF) is a curve that illustrates the maximum feasible amount of two goods that a country can produce, given its resources and technology. It shows the trade-offs between the two goods. The opportunity cost is represented by the slope of the PPF. When producing more of one good, the opportunity cost is the amount of the other good that must be given up. This concept helps in understanding the efficiency and allocation of resources in an economy.
How do you determine the correct price for trade between two parties?
To determine the correct price for trade, the price must lie between the opportunity costs of the two trading partners. This ensures that both parties benefit from the trade. For example, if the opportunity cost of 1 pizza roll is between 1 and 2 hunch punches, a fair trade price could be 1.5 hunch punches per pizza roll. Factors like supply and demand, negotiating power, and equity can also influence the final trade price.
What factors influence the final trade price between two parties?
Several factors influence the final trade price between two parties: 1) Supply and demand: If one good is more abundant, its value may be lower. 2) Negotiating power: A better negotiator can secure a more favorable trade. 3) Equity: Ensuring that both parties feel the trade is fair and beneficial. These factors help determine where within the opportunity cost range the final trade price will fall.
Why must the price of trade lie between the opportunity costs of the trading partners?
The price of trade must lie between the opportunity costs of the trading partners to ensure that both parties benefit from the exchange. If the price is outside this range, one party would be better off producing the good themselves rather than trading. For example, if the opportunity cost of 1 pizza roll is 1 to 2 hunch punches, trading at 1.5 hunch punches per pizza roll ensures both parties gain from the trade.
How does negotiating power affect the trade price?
Negotiating power affects the trade price by allowing the stronger negotiator to secure a more favorable deal. If one party has better negotiation skills or more leverage, they can push the trade price closer to their preferred end of the opportunity cost range. This can result in a trade price that benefits them more, while still being within the acceptable range for the other party.