So, let's continue the discussion on the relationship between the money market and the aggregate demand curve by including the entire aggregate demand aggregate supply model. This is the AD-AS model that we've learned previously. We're going to see how the money market affects this model. So, remember, the Fed has two main goals when it comes to monetary policy: managing the employment level in the economy and ensuring price stability, right? They want high employment and they don't want prices to go out of control through high inflation. So, when the economy is in recession, real GDP is below its potential output. We're in a recession; the spending is low, and there's not as much GDP happening as we would want.
During this recession, we see cyclical unemployment. So, there's a lot of unemployment and there's low investment going on which is affecting aggregate demand, right? This investment causes aggregate demand to be down because there isn't much investment happening during the recession. So, the Fed is going to employ what's called expansionary monetary policy. They want the economy to expand. Right? "Expansionary" means they want more GDP. They want GDP to increase. So, how do they get GDP to increase? They want to entice investment. So, how can they entice investment by managing the interest rate? They can lower the interest rate, right? If they can get a lower interest rate in the economy, well, it's going to entice businesses to spend money, right? There's low interest; they can make investments in long-term purchases because they can take out loans at a lower cost.
So, let's look at how an expansionary monetary policy looks like in the money market and our AD-AS model. We're in a recession. Right? Let's look at our AD-AS model and let's label it real quick. In our AD-AS model, we have our price level and our GDP. Right? The real GDP on our x-axis. Let's get out of the way. What curves are on our graph here? We've got our long-run aggregate supply, our short-run aggregate supply, and our aggregate demand curve. Right? There's no short-run or long-run with the aggregate demand. We just have one curve there. Notice what's happening here. Our short-run equilibrium where the aggregate demand and the short-run aggregate supply are lower than our long-run equilibrium GDP, right? In the short run, I'm going to say short-run equilibrium is going to have a lower GDP, right? Lower GDP because we're in a recession, right? The short-run equilibrium has this lower amount of GDP and this is the price level currently. So, we'll say P1 here in this case.
Now, what does the Fed want to do? The Fed wants to employ expansionary monetary policy. They want to get us back to this higher level of GDP, our long-run equilibrium level of GDP. They want to increase the amount of GDP and, like we said, they're going to lower the interest rate to stimulate the economy. Okay? So, how are they going to do that? First, look into the money market. Remember, in the money market, we have our interest rate on the Y-axis and we've got the quantity of money here on the x-axis, right? The interest rate, being the price of money, and they want to bring the interest rate down. Right now, the money supply is here at MS1. The money demand is here, and we've got this equilibrium interest rate right here, R1.
So, they want to bring the interest rate down, right? They want the interest rate lower to stimulate the economy and increase investment. So, they want to bring it down here to R2. What do they have to do in the money supply to get to this new equilibrium interest rate? Do they need to increase or decrease the money supply? They need to increase the money supply, right? By having a higher money supply, then we would have a new equilibrium down where we want it at R2. This new money supply by expanding the money supply will have the new equilibrium at this lower rate, which is R2. Right? So, that would be their target is to increase the money supply by that much to lower the interest rate by that much. So, what are they going to do in this case? Do they buy or sell Treasury securities? Remember, this is always the case: the Fed is either buying or selling Treasury securities from the public to affect the money supply. So, the Fed is giving something to the public and the public is giving something to the Fed here. The Fed is either giving up money or getting money. They want to increase the money supply, right? So, they want to increase the money in the hands of the public. So, they're going to give money to the public in this case, and they're going to get securities, right? They're going to purchase the securities. So, in this case, they're purchasing securities to increase the money supply, which leads to a lower interest rate.
Okay? So, this is how all of these moving pieces work, right? We're starting with the purchase of securities, which leads to a higher money supply, which leads to a lower interest rate, and this lower interest rate, how is it going to affect our AD-AS model? This is the final piece of the puzzle. This is why the Fed did all of this: because they want to affect the AD-AS model and get us back to our long-run GDP equilibrium. So, at this lower interest rate, we already said that it's going to affect investment, right? There's an increase in investment, but there's also increases in consumption and net exports, as well. All of those are affected by the lower_interest_rate. The lower interest rate leads to higher consumption, higher investment, higher net exports; all of these moving parts. So the goal of the Fed is to shift the aggregate demand curve. They want the aggregate demand curve to increase. So, they're enticing people to spend more money, not just the citizens, but the firms as well, and foreigners as well. So in this case, what's going to happen is the aggregate demand curve is going to shift to the right. We're going to have this shift to the right, to this new equilibrium over here; we'll get it to cross in the middle there. This is our aggregate demand 2. So, the final piece of the puzzle there, leading to our new long-run equilibrium right here. So, our long-run equilibrium right here; we're now back to our full potential of GDP in our long-run equilibrium. But what's happened to the price level? In this long-run equilibrium, we find that we have a higher price level, right? A higher price level in this long-run equilibrium. So, there are a lot of moving parts there, right? We saw a lot of things happening, but it all comes down to what open market operation did the Fed do, how does that affect our money market, and the relationship between the level of the interest rate and aggregate demand as well. Alright? So now, let's see the opposite: where the Fed wants to employ contractionary monetary policy. Let's see it in...