Alright, so we've seen how the government can help provide solutions to externalities; now let's see how solutions can be found privately without government intervention. When we talk about private solutions to externalities, we're always going to talk about the Coase theorem, okay? The Coase theorem was developed by Ronald Coase, who also won a Nobel Prize for his ideas relating to solutions to externalities. So that's the connection you should always make, and that's what his ideas were: that the parties can privately come up with a solution if certain conditions are met. The first condition being that the property rights are clearly defined. Remember how we talked about how important property rights are? In this case, this is going to be essential that property rights are clearly defined, and second, that the transaction costs are low. When I talk about transaction costs, this includes the time, the money, coordination efforts; all of this has to be pretty minimal for this to work. If high transaction costs exist, like a language barrier between the people negotiating requiring a translator, it can prevent a private solution from arising. Let's go back and talk about this with an example involving a barking dog, which started our whole discussion about externalities.
In this first case, let's discuss the benefit the owner has for owning the dog. It's hard to quantify these things because it's an intangible concept, but let's say the owner's benefit from owning a dog is equivalent to $500—the amount of joy as if someone had just handed them $500. The neighbor's cost from this dog's barking is $800 due to the lost sleep, stress, and loss of happiness the noise causes. In a scenario where there's no noise ordinance, and the owner has the property rights over the noise, a possible solution under the Coase theorem might be the neighbor paying the owner $600 to get rid of the dog. Here, the $600 the neighbor is willing to pay exceeds the $500 worth of happiness the owner gets from the dog, making the owner willing to accept the offer and rid of the dog, satisfying both parties. This is an example of finding an efficient solution without government interaction.
Now, let’s consider a different scenario where the owner values the dog at $1,000 worth of happiness. With the cost to the neighbor still at $800 and the owner still possessing property rights, no transaction will occur. The neighbor's maximum willingness to pay ($800) is less than the value the dog brings to the owner ($1,000). Thus, there will be no agreement, and the neighbor will have to tolerate the noise, considering it a factor when they chose to move in, an efficient outcome under these specific conditions.
In the last example, we keep the same values, but now let's assume the neighbor has the property rights due to a noise ordinance. Here, the owner could offer $900 to the neighbor to keep the dog, an offer that provides both parties with a benefit exceeding their respective costs. Again, an efficient outcome is reached, proving that as long as property rights are clearly defined and transaction costs are low, private solutions to externalities can effectively be reached without government intervention.
This was Coase's Nobel Prize-winning idea: that efficient solutions to externalities can be achieved privately, without government intervention, as long as property rights are clearly defined and transaction costs are minimal. So, anytime you hear about the Coase theorem, think about externalities and the potential for private solutions. Now, let's move on to some practice problems in the next video.