Now let's discuss how the elasticity of the curves relates to the taxes. Alright, so the way we're going to split the tax, right? The tax incidence to the consumer and the tax incidence to the producer is going to be based on the price elasticity of the curves, right? So remember when we were talking about price elasticity, so if we're talking about price elasticity of demand, price elasticity of demand, that was when we had the percentage change in quantity demanded over the percentage change in price, right? And with supply, it was quantity supplied on top. So this idea of elasticity, it helped us determine what the shape of the curve was going to look like, right? How kind of like how steep the curves are going to be kind of thing, right? So remember from our earlier discussion about taxes is that the party paying the tax does not necessarily bear the burden, right? Just because the buyer is paying the tax doesn't mean that they're going to take the whole burden. It's going to be split in some way and that split is going to be based on these elasticities. So let's look at a couple of examples. First, let's look at a situation where we have an elastic supply and an inelastic demand, right? So, demand is more inelastic and let's look on the graph and let's talk about this. So we've got our price and quantity axes and this is our downward demand and our supply curve, right? So it tells us that the supply is elastic which we know because it's crossing here, through the price axis, right? And the other thing that tells me that it's elastic is that it's very close to laying down. Remember when we're perfectly elastic, we're laying down and the supply curve is pretty close to that laying down so it's pretty elastic there. And how about the demand curve, right? That's pretty close to perfectly inelastic where we're standing straight up, it's just a little bit over to the side, so that one's quite inelastic. So look what happens to our tax in this situation. So remember, we're going to impose some tax that's going to put a difference between the prices the buyers pay up here and the price the seller receives down here, right? There's now this difference because of the tax and we're going to be able to say who paid more of the tax based on who has more of the line, right? So if this was our original \( p^{\ast} \) right here, right and I'll draw it in black this whole line to divide that tax. So the amount below the line is the part that goes to the supplier and you can see it's a little tiny piece right? This little red piece right there, that's going to the supplier and that big chunk is going to the buyer, right. So in this case, you're going to see that the buyer pays more. I'm going to say, pays more, right? They're going to have a higher tax incidence in this case. And now let's talk about the others, the opposite situation where we have an inelastic supply and an elastic demand. So once again right we've got our price and quantity axes and our demand downward and our supply upward. And again, let's confirm that we're inelastic or elastic, right? So supply is inelastic when it crosses the quantity axis which we see there, but we also can kind of confirm because it's almost perfectly inelastic, right? It's getting close to that standing straight up and we got elastic demand, right? It's getting pretty close to that perfectly elastic laying down. So that is our elastic demand that we see there. And now what happens? So we're going to have the same situation where there's this tax imposed, right? And we're going to have this difference where the price of the buyer is right here and the price of the seller is down here, right, and there's that tax in the middle. So just like we did before, let's see who's paying more of the tax in this situation, right? So the portion of the tax going to the buyer in this case is a little bit, on the top is small, right, compared to this large amount to the seller, right? So in this case, the seller is paying more. They have the higher tax incidence. Seller pays more, pays more and I'm going to_write_tax_on_each_of_these_just_to_be_clear, pays more tax, right? Okay. So what have we seen? What conclusion can we draw here, right? In both cases, in the first case we had inelastic demand and the buyer was paying more tax. In the second case we had inelastic supply and the seller was paying more tax, right? So we're going to make this conclusion that whoever is more elastic or excuse me, more inelastic, right? Whoever was more inelastic represents the group that will have more tax incidents, right? And the idea here is let's think about back to elasticity, right? When we're inelastic that means that our quantity demanded is not going to react so much to a price change, right? We're usually inelastic as consumers for something that we really need, right? Maybe like some sort of life-saving drug or if we're addicted to cigarettes, right? Cigarettes would be an inelastic demand that even if the price went up, we would still buy them. So that would that would be an inelastic product and you can imagine if you're inelastic and the price is changing, you can't really get out of the market. But if you're elastic and now you're seeing this higher price, you're going to get out of the market and that's exactly what we're seeing. So whoever's more inelastic is kind of more tied to the market and is going to have to suffer through that tax incidence. Alright, so whoever's more inelastic is more, has more tax incidence. So if the demand curve is more inelastic, consumers have a higher tax incidence. Consumers pay more tax, and if the supply curve is more inelastic, the sellers pay more tax. Right? Now up in our example, we had a situation where, one was elastic and the other one was inelastic, right? What if they're both elastic or they're both inelastic? How do we know who's going to share, the burden? Well in that case when they're both elastic or both inelastic, you're going to get something closer to a fair share, right? Where they're going to be splitting it more evenly. But remember it's the one that's more inelastic that's going to pay more. So even if they're both elastic, one might be more inelastic than the other. And in_that_case_they're_going_to_pay_more_of_the_tax, right? And usually you're not going to have to be able to decide that, usually it's going to be some sort of visual thing like we can see on this graph here, right? So more inelastic, more tax incidents, alright? So in the next video let's go through a couple of special cases, like the idea of having perfect perfectly elastic demand or perfectly inelastic demand and let's see what happens with tax incidents in those cases. Alright, let's do that now.
- 0. Basic Principles of Economics1h 5m
- Introduction to Economics3m
- People Are Rational2m
- People Respond to Incentives1m
- Scarcity and Choice2m
- Marginal Analysis9m
- Allocative Efficiency, Productive Efficiency, and Equality7m
- Positive and Normative Analysis7m
- Microeconomics vs. Macroeconomics2m
- Factors of Production5m
- Circular Flow Diagram5m
- Graphing Review10m
- Percentage and Decimal Review4m
- Fractions Review2m
- 1. Reading and Understanding Graphs59m
- 2. Introductory Economic Models1h 10m
- 3. The Market Forces of Supply and Demand2h 26m
- Competitive Markets10m
- The Demand Curve13m
- Shifts in the Demand Curve24m
- Movement Along a Demand Curve5m
- The Supply Curve9m
- Shifts in the Supply Curve22m
- Movement Along a Supply Curve3m
- Market Equilibrium8m
- Using the Supply and Demand Curves to Find Equilibrium3m
- Effects of Surplus3m
- Effects of Shortage2m
- Supply and Demand: Quantitative Analysis40m
- 4. Elasticity2h 16m
- Percentage Change and Price Elasticity of Demand10m
- Elasticity and the Midpoint Method20m
- Price Elasticity of Demand on a Graph11m
- Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand6m
- Total Revenue Test13m
- Total Revenue Along a Linear Demand Curve14m
- Income Elasticity of Demand23m
- Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand11m
- Price Elasticity of Supply12m
- Price Elasticity of Supply on a Graph3m
- Elasticity Summary9m
- 5. Consumer and Producer Surplus; Price Ceilings and Floors3h 45m
- Consumer Surplus and Willingness to Pay38m
- Producer Surplus and Willingness to Sell26m
- Economic Surplus and Efficiency18m
- Quantitative Analysis of Consumer and Producer Surplus at Equilibrium28m
- Price Ceilings, Price Floors, and Black Markets38m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Price Floors: Finding Points20m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Price Floors: Finding Areas54m
- 6. Introduction to Taxes and Subsidies1h 46m
- 7. Externalities1h 12m
- 8. The Types of Goods1h 13m
- 9. International Trade1h 16m
- 10. The Costs of Production2h 35m
- 11. Perfect Competition2h 23m
- Introduction to the Four Market Models2m
- Characteristics of Perfect Competition6m
- Revenue in Perfect Competition14m
- Perfect Competition Profit on the Graph20m
- Short Run Shutdown Decision33m
- Long Run Entry and Exit Decision18m
- Individual Supply Curve in the Short Run and Long Run6m
- Market Supply Curve in the Short Run and Long Run9m
- Long Run Equilibrium12m
- Perfect Competition and Efficiency15m
- Four Market Model Summary: Perfect Competition5m
- 12. Monopoly2h 13m
- Characteristics of Monopoly21m
- Monopoly Revenue12m
- Monopoly Profit on the Graph16m
- Monopoly Efficiency and Deadweight Loss20m
- Price Discrimination22m
- Antitrust Laws and Government Regulation of Monopolies11m
- Mergers and the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI)17m
- Four Firm Concentration Ratio6m
- Four Market Model Summary: Monopoly4m
- 13. Monopolistic Competition1h 9m
- 14. Oligopoly1h 26m
- 15. Markets for the Factors of Production1h 33m
- The Production Function and Marginal Revenue Product16m
- Demand for Labor in Perfect Competition7m
- Shifts in Labor Demand13m
- Supply of Labor in Perfect Competition7m
- Shifts in Labor Supply5m
- Differences in Wages6m
- Discrimination6m
- Other Factors of Production: Land and Capital5m
- Unions6m
- Monopsony11m
- Bilateral Monopoly5m
- 16. Income Inequality and Poverty35m
- 17. Asymmetric Information, Voting, and Public Choice39m
- 18. Consumer Choice and Behavioral Economics1h 16m
Elasticity and Taxes - Online Tutor, Practice Problems & Exam Prep
The tax incidence on consumers and producers is influenced by the price elasticity of demand and supply. When demand is inelastic, consumers bear a higher tax burden, while inelastic supply shifts the burden to sellers. In extreme cases, perfectly elastic demand means sellers absorb the entire tax, whereas perfectly inelastic demand results in buyers bearing the full burden. Understanding these dynamics is crucial for analyzing market behavior and the effects of taxation on economic outcomes.
The tax incidence to the consumer and producer depend on the price elasticity of each curve.
Elasticity and Taxes
Video transcript
Elasticity and Taxes:Perfectly Elastic Demand and Perfectly Inelastic Demand
Video transcript
Alright, so now let's talk about these special cases: perfectly elastic and perfectly inelastic. Right, so first we have a perfectly elastic demand, right? It's laying down entirely. It's super elastic. It's laying down. It's so comfy, right? And we've got our supply curve just kind of a standard supply curve, right? So what happens if, let's say, there's a tax here, right? Let's put the tax on suppliers and shift the supply curve to the left. And let's think about what happens here. So this is S2, this was S1, right? So now when demand is perfectly elastic, they're willing to buy any quantity, right, but they're only willing to buy it at a specific price. They're not going to pay more for this than this price that we see here. So what's going to happen to this tax burden? If the supplier tries to shift any of the burden to the consumers, they're not going to have it; they're not going to buy anymore, right? At a different price, they wouldn't purchase any. So in this case, the supplier is going to have to bear the entire burden of the tax. The seller bears the entire burden of the tax. So the price to the buyers is going to stay the same, and the price to the seller is going to decrease by the full amount of the tax.
So let's talk about the other situation. What about when we have perfectly inelastic demand and just a regular supply curve there? So now we're talking about that situation where it's like a life-saving drug or something that we need to have, no matter what the price, right? So now in this case, let's say there was a tax on the supplier, right? Just to keep it simple. Now what's going to happen is that since it's perfectly inelastic, the buyers are willing to pay any price, and they are going to take the full burden of the tax themselves, right? So in this case, the buyer takes the full burden, and this makes sense back to our previous conclusion where the more inelastic curve pays more tax. In the first case, who was more inelastic? Well, demand was perfectly elastic. You couldn't get any more elastic. So anything is going to be more inelastic than that, right? So the supply curve was more inelastic, and they paid more of the tax. In this case, it's the extreme example that they paid all of it. How about the other side? Here we have perfectly inelastic demand, right? You can't get any more inelastic than perfectly inelastic, and in that case, they're more inelastic than the other one, right? And so that's what we're seeing here. Since the demand is more inelastic and, in this case, perfectly inelastic, they're going to have more of the tax burden, and in this case, all of the tax burden. Alright, so our conclusion stays the same even at these extremes; it's just that the entire burden is being put on 1 person. Alright, so that's about it for these special cases, let's go ahead to the next video.
A tax imposed on consumers of a good:
Suppose that a unit tax of $2 is imposed on producers with initial equilibrium of $10. If the demand curve is vertical and the supply curve is upward-sloping, what will be the price faced by consumers after the tax?
Here’s what students ask on this topic:
How does price elasticity of demand affect tax incidence?
Price elasticity of demand significantly influences tax incidence. When demand is inelastic, consumers are less sensitive to price changes, meaning they will continue to buy the product even if the price increases due to a tax. As a result, consumers bear a higher tax burden. Conversely, if demand is elastic, consumers are more sensitive to price changes and will reduce their quantity demanded if the price rises. In this case, producers bear a larger share of the tax burden because they cannot pass the tax onto consumers without losing sales. Understanding this relationship helps in predicting who will bear the cost of a tax in different market scenarios.
What happens to tax incidence when supply is perfectly inelastic?
When supply is perfectly inelastic, producers cannot change the quantity supplied regardless of the price. In this scenario, producers bear the entire tax burden. This is because they cannot reduce the quantity supplied to avoid the tax, and they cannot pass the tax onto consumers without losing sales. The price received by producers decreases by the full amount of the tax, while the price paid by consumers remains unchanged. This situation is often seen in markets for essential goods where production cannot be easily adjusted.
Why do consumers bear more tax burden when demand is inelastic?
Consumers bear more tax burden when demand is inelastic because their quantity demanded does not significantly decrease with a price increase. Inelastic demand means that consumers need or strongly desire the product, such as life-saving medications or addictive goods like cigarettes. Since consumers will continue to purchase nearly the same amount despite higher prices, producers can pass most or all of the tax onto consumers. This results in consumers paying a higher portion of the tax, as their purchasing behavior is less responsive to price changes.
How does perfectly elastic demand impact tax incidence?
With perfectly elastic demand, consumers are highly sensitive to price changes and will only buy the product at a specific price. If a tax is imposed, producers cannot pass any of the tax onto consumers because even a slight price increase would result in zero sales. Therefore, producers must absorb the entire tax burden. The price received by producers decreases by the full amount of the tax, while the price paid by consumers remains constant. This scenario illustrates how extreme elasticity can shift the entire tax burden onto one party.
What is the relationship between elasticity and tax burden in a market?
The relationship between elasticity and tax burden in a market is that the more inelastic side of the market (whether demand or supply) bears a greater share of the tax burden. If demand is more inelastic than supply, consumers will bear a larger portion of the tax. Conversely, if supply is more inelastic than demand, producers will bear a larger portion of the tax. This occurs because the inelastic side cannot easily change its quantity demanded or supplied in response to price changes, making it less able to avoid the tax.