Alright, so now let's do a similar example, but now we're in the long run. Notice how our terminology has changed here a little bit. A farmer is considering whether he should continue to rent a field for the upcoming season at a price of $1,000, right? So in this case, he doesn't have the field rented already. When we talked about the short run, he had already paid for the field and he was going to have it no matter what for the season, right? So in this case, he can decide whether or not he wants to pay for the field, right? The seeds still cost $200 here, and we have to decide whether or not the farmer should produce, right? So in the first case, we see that revenues from sales are $500 just like last time, and we're going to see what happens when revenues are $100 as well. Okay, so in this case, if they don't produce, right? Before when he didn't produce, he had to eat the cost of the field, right? That $1,000 for the field, he had already paid it. There was nothing he could do about it. But now in this case, he hasn't paid for the field yet, right? He's deciding whether or not he wants to rent it. So, if he doesn't produce, he doesn't have to pay for the field, and he has zero profit but zero loss as well, right? Now, what if he does decide to produce? If he does decide, he's going to have to pay for the field, right? Well, first revenue, right? If he does produce, he's going to bring in 500 in revenue, but now his total cost, he's going to have to pay for the field. Right? He's going to have to pay the $1,000 for the field and $200 for the seeds. Total cost of $1,200, right? This is similar to what we saw before, and his profit is going to be that $500 minus the $1,200, and he's going to lose $700 in this case, right? Last time when we were talking about the short run, this was the better option, right? Because he was losing less money than if he paid for the field and didn't produce, but now he doesn't even have to pay for the field. So the best scenario in this case is no production, no loss, right? He's going to have no loss, no profit either, but he's not going to lose money, right? This was a losing venture, he can finally get out, and this is his chance to exit the market.
Alright, what about if we have lower revenue? Well, you can imagine this is going to be an even worse case, right?
So if he doesn't produce, again 0, right? He's not going to have any profit or loss. He doesn't have to pay for the fields. He doesn’t have to pay for the seeds. He doesn’t bring in any money. So he's got 0 there.
Now, what if he does produce? Well, his revenue will be the $100 from the sales, and his total cost, well, he's going to have to pay for the field, $1,000, and he's going to have to pay $200 for the seeds. So, he's got $1,200 in total costs there. His profit, or rather his loss, is going to be $100 minus $1,200, which is a negative $1,100, right? Revenue minus cost there, negative $1,100. Okay. So again, his best case scenario is no production here. He shouldn't produce again, and that is because he couldn't cover his costs, right? So now notice what happened is that all of our costs are relevant, right? We were able to get out of paying for the field as well. So what we're going to see in this long-run decision is that we're going to shut down when the price falls below the minimum, and this time it's not the Average Variable Cost (AVC); it's the Average Total Cost (ATC), right? Because all the costs are relevant and we can get out of say renting the field in this case, right?
So they don't have a name for this like they did in the short run; they had the shutdown point for that minimum point on the AVC. Well, they don’t really have a name like that; it’s the entry-exit point, right. Any point below that, we are going to exit the market entirely, okay. So this is a long-run decision if our long-run Average Total Cost (ATC) is greater than our price, right? We can't cover those costs in the long run. There's just no way for us to make money. So let's go ahead and finish up right now, as we saw that we're going to exit, right if our total revenue, the money we’re bringing in, can't cover our total cost in the long run, right. Total revenue less than total cost, we’re out of here, we exit. So let's do the same thing and divide, right? Total revenue divided by q, right? We’re going to find the average of each and total cost divided by q, and what was our average revenue? Just like last time, right? Average revenue is just price, as we discovered in our revenue video, so our left side of the equation becomes price, and we're going to exit if that price is less than our Average Total Cost (ATC), right. And just here behind me, I'll move to the side. We're going to enter the opposite, right? If the price is greater than Average Total Cost (ATC), right? If that price is greater than Average Total Cost, firms are going to see, hey, we can make money here. Let's go ahead and join this market. We're going to see the implications of this entering and exiting of the market in other videos, but for now, what we see is that for long-run decisions, it’s that Average Total Cost curve that matters again, right? So Average Variable Cost curve doesn't matter for the long-run decision. We want to see the Average Total Cost, okay? So let’s go ahead and pause right here and in the next video, let’s discuss all of these points on the graph, alright? Let’s discuss what can happen at different price levels. Cool? Alright, let’s do that now.