Now let's talk about another elasticity of demand, the cross-price elasticity of demand. So the cross-price elasticity of demand helps us gauge whether goods are going to be substitutes or complements or just completely unrelated, right? Remember when we were talking about substitutes and complements in the demand shifts, the idea was that the price change in one good would affect the demand of another, right? And that's exactly what we see in our formula here, right? Look at our formula for cross-price elasticity of demand. We've got the quantity demanded of one good in the numerator, right? Notice how quantity demanded is still in the numerator just like always, but we've got the price of a different good here, Good Y, right? So quantity demanded of one good, price of another good, right? The idea here is we're going to see how quantity demanded of one good reacts to the change in the price of another good, and you can imagine that it's going to help us find substitutes and complements, right. So still just like before, we're going to keep using our midpoint method and luckily again the steps stay 99% the same, except in this case, we're using the price of a different good rather than the price of our own good. Just like with the income elasticity too, the only thing that changes we were using income instead of price, now we're using the price of another good instead of the price of our good. And once again, you can tell right here price and price in the denominator, they all kind of follow this flow. Whatever the name of it is, that's what's in the denominator, but it's also easy to just remember that quantity is always going to be in the numerator for all of our elasticities. Alright, so let's go ahead and do an example here for cross-price elasticity. You're going to see how similar our steps are and again with this one, we do have the positive and negative, differences, right? So we're going to end up making our conclusion based on it being positive or negative, so that's going to matter in this case as well. So, let's go ahead and do an example where we can use our steps, which are basically the same as we've been using. When the price of tennis rackets increased from $45 to $55 the quantity demanded of tennis balls dropped from 21,000 to 19,000. What is the cross-price elasticity of demand? So notice they gave us two quantities, right, but those are quantities of tennis balls and they gave us two prices. But those are prices of tennis racquets. Right? So, you can imagine that these are going to be complements, like I picked things that sound like complements, just for the sake of it, but, we can make sure by doing this calculation. But the idea here is we're seeing a price increase in one product and a quantity demanded decrease in the other product, right? So remember from demand shifts, that's exactly what happens with a complement. If the price goes up of a complement, the quantity demanded of the complement goes down, right? So in this case, that's exactly what we're seeing. Let's do our steps and do the analysis with elasticity. So we'll make two columns quantity demanded and that's quantity demanded of tennis balls and P that's our price column for the price of tennis racquets, and let's go ahead and do this. So first, we subtract 21,000 minus 19,000 equals 2,000. And price, the same thing. 55 minus 45 equals 10. Step 2, we're gonna add, 21,000 +19,000 equals 40,000. And on the other side, the same, 55 + 45 equals 100. Now step 3 is where we're gonna divide step 2 by 2. 40,000 divided by 2 equals 20,000. And on the other side, 100 divided by 2 equals 50. Step 4, this is where we're gonna get our actual percentage changes in each. So step 1 divided by step 3, 2,000 divided by 20,000 is going to equal 0.1. That's our percentage change in quantity demanded. Let's do the same thing with price. So we've got 10 divided by 50 and we're gonna have 0.2 as a percentage change in price, right? Now we haven't dealt with the positives or negatives yet, I always leave that for the last step where I go back to the problem. So first let's get the number of our cross-price elasticity which is just gonna be this quantity demanded 0.1, right? This is quantity divided by price, which was the 0.2 and we are going to get an answer of 0.5 right there, right. Half. So now we just have to check, is it positive or negative? So let's see for the prices, we had a price increase so the price is a positive and for tennis balls, the quantity decreased, right, dropped from 21 to 19. So that one's negative right there. So we have a negative and a positive, that means it's a negative. We have a negative 0.5 for our answer. So now how do we analyze this answer that we just got, negative 0.5? Well, right down here we've got our answers. So if it's positive, then we know they're substitutes. If it's negative, they're complements, and if it's zero, then you know they're unrelated. Okay? So in this case, we got a negative number which tells us that they are complements, but remember we can use some logic to kind of come to the same conclusion, right? We saw the price of tennis rackets go up and the quantity demanded of tennis balls go down, right? So the idea is if you remember from the demand shifts, when the price of one product goes up causing the other quantity demanded to go down, that means that they're going to be complements. Now if the price had gone up and the quantity demanded of the other one went up, that's when we're talking about substitutes and that's why you would see a positive answer in this case, up and up, right? So really in this case, you can make a lot of conclusions just from the problem without doing any math. Alright? So let's go ahead and do some practice problems about cross-price elasticity.
- 1. Introduction to Macroeconomics1h 57m
- 2. Introductory Economic Models59m
- 3. Supply and Demand3h 43m
- Introduction to Supply and Demand10m
- The Basics of Demand7m
- Individual Demand and Market Demand6m
- Shifting Demand44m
- The Basics of Supply3m
- Individual Supply and Market Supply6m
- Shifting Supply28m
- Big Daddy Shift Summary8m
- Supply and Demand Together: Equilibrium, Shortage, and Surplus10m
- Supply and Demand Together: One-sided Shifts22m
- Supply and Demand Together: Both Shift34m
- Supply and Demand: Quantitative Analysis40m
- 4. Elasticity2h 26m
- Percentage Change and Price Elasticity of Demand19m
- Elasticity and the Midpoint Method20m
- Price Elasticity of Demand on a Graph11m
- Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand6m
- Total Revenue Test13m
- Total Revenue Along a Linear Demand Curve14m
- Income Elasticity of Demand23m
- Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand11m
- Price Elasticity of Supply12m
- Price Elasticity of Supply on a Graph3m
- Elasticity Summary9m
- 5. Consumer and Producer Surplus; Price Ceilings and Price Floors3h 40m
- Consumer Surplus and WIllingness to Pay33m
- Producer Surplus and Willingness to Sell26m
- Economic Surplus and Efficiency18m
- Quantitative Analysis of Consumer and Producer Surplus at Equilibrium28m
- Price Ceilings, Price Floors, and Black Markets38m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Floors: Finding Points20m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Floors: Finding Areas54m
- 6. Introduction to Taxes1h 25m
- 7. Externalities1h 3m
- 8. The Types of Goods1h 13m
- 9. International Trade1h 16m
- 10. Introducing Economic Concepts49m
- Introducing Concepts - Business Cycle7m
- Introducing Concepts - Nominal GDP and Real GDP12m
- Introducing Concepts - Unemployment and Inflation3m
- Introducing Concepts - Economic Growth6m
- Introducing Concepts - Savings and Investment5m
- Introducing Concepts - Trade Deficit and Surplus6m
- Introducing Concepts - Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy7m
- 11. Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and Consumer Price Index (CPI)1h 37m
- Calculating GDP11m
- Detailed Explanation of GDP Components9m
- Value Added Method for Measuring GDP1m
- Nominal GDP and Real GDP22m
- Shortcomings of GDP8m
- Calculating GDP Using the Income Approach10m
- Other Measures of Total Production and Total Income5m
- Consumer Price Index (CPI)13m
- Using CPI to Adjust for Inflation7m
- Problems with the Consumer Price Index (CPI)6m
- 12. Unemployment and Inflation1h 22m
- Labor Force and Unemployment9m
- Types of Unemployment12m
- Labor Unions and Collective Bargaining6m
- Unemployment: Minimum Wage Laws and Efficiency Wages7m
- Unemployment Trends7m
- Nominal Interest, Real Interest, and the Fisher Equation10m
- Nominal Income and Real Income12m
- Who is Affected by Inflation?5m
- Demand-Pull and Cost-Push Inflation6m
- Costs of Inflation: Shoe-leather Costs and Menu Costs4m
- 13. Productivity and Economic Growth1h 17m
- 14. The Financial System1h 37m
- 15. Income and Consumption52m
- 16. Deriving the Aggregate Expenditures Model1h 22m
- 17. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis1h 18m
- 18. The Monetary System1h 1m
- The Functions of Money; The Kinds of Money8m
- Defining the Money Supply: M1 and M24m
- Required Reserves and the Deposit Multiplier8m
- Introduction to the Federal Reserve8m
- The Federal Reserve and the Money Supply11m
- History of the US Banking System9m
- The Financial Crisis of 2007-2009 (The Great Recession)10m
- 19. Monetary Policy1h 32m
- 20. Fiscal Policy1h 0m
- 21. Revisiting Inflation, Unemployment, and Policy46m
- 22. Balance of Payments30m
- 23. Exchange Rates1h 16m
- Exchange Rates: Introduction14m
- Exchange Rates: Nominal and Real13m
- Exchange Rates: Equilibrium6m
- Exchange Rates: Shifts in Supply and Demand11m
- Exchange Rates and Net Exports6m
- Exchange Rates: Fixed, Flexible, and Managed Float5m
- Exchange Rates: Purchasing Power Parity7m
- The Gold Standard4m
- The Bretton Woods System6m
- 24. Macroeconomic Schools of Thought40m
- 25. Dynamic AD/AS Model35m
- 26. Special Topics11m
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand: Study with Video Lessons, Practice Problems & Examples
Cross price elasticity of demand measures how the quantity demanded of one good responds to the price change of another good, indicating whether they are substitutes, complements, or unrelated. The formula involves the quantity demanded of one good in the numerator and the price of another good in the denominator. A negative result indicates complements, while a positive result suggests substitutes. For example, if the price of tennis rackets rises and the quantity demanded for tennis balls falls, the cross price elasticity is negative, confirming they are complements.
Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand
Video transcript
An increase in the demand for chicken, from 8,000 to 12,000, was caused by an increase in the price of beef from $4.50 to $5.50. Therefore, the cross-price elasticity for these two products is:
Here’s what students ask on this topic:
What is cross-price elasticity of demand and how is it calculated?
Cross-price elasticity of demand measures how the quantity demanded of one good responds to a price change in another good. It helps determine if goods are substitutes, complements, or unrelated. The formula is:
Where is the change in quantity demanded of Good X, is the initial quantity demanded of Good X, is the change in price of Good Y, and is the initial price of Good Y. A positive result indicates substitutes, a negative result indicates complements, and a zero result indicates unrelated goods.
How do you interpret the sign of cross-price elasticity of demand?
The sign of the cross-price elasticity of demand indicates the relationship between two goods. A positive cross-price elasticity suggests that the goods are substitutes, meaning that an increase in the price of one good leads to an increase in the quantity demanded of the other. A negative cross-price elasticity indicates that the goods are complements, meaning that an increase in the price of one good leads to a decrease in the quantity demanded of the other. If the cross-price elasticity is zero, the goods are unrelated, meaning that a price change in one good does not affect the quantity demanded of the other.
Can you provide an example of calculating cross-price elasticity of demand?
Sure! Let's say the price of tennis rackets increases from $45 to $55, and as a result, the quantity demanded of tennis balls decreases from 21,000 to 19,000. First, calculate the percentage change in quantity demanded and price:
Then, divide the percentage change in quantity demanded by the percentage change in price:
The cross-price elasticity of demand is -0.43, indicating that tennis rackets and tennis balls are complements.
What are some real-world examples of substitutes and complements?
Real-world examples of substitutes include tea and coffee, where an increase in the price of coffee may lead to an increase in the demand for tea. Another example is butter and margarine. For complements, consider smartphones and apps; an increase in the price of smartphones may decrease the demand for apps. Another example is cars and gasoline; if the price of cars increases, the demand for gasoline may decrease as fewer people buy cars.
Why is cross-price elasticity of demand important in economics?
Cross-price elasticity of demand is important because it helps businesses and policymakers understand the relationships between different goods. For businesses, knowing whether products are substitutes or complements can inform pricing strategies, marketing, and product development. For policymakers, understanding these relationships can help in assessing the impact of taxes, subsidies, and regulations on different markets. It also aids in predicting consumer behavior and market dynamics, which is crucial for making informed economic decisions.