Now, let's see how the multiplier effect comes into play when we have a change in government spending. So we're dealing with fiscal policy and the multiplier effect describes this chain reaction. First, there's going to be an initial boost in government spending, which leads to a much higher increase in GDP. Now it can go the other way too. A decrease in government spending can lead to a much higher decrease in GDP for the same reason, this multiplier effect. Okay? Now I want to make a note. You've probably heard of the multiplier effect before and if you haven't, that's okay. The multiplier effect affects all the parts of GDP. So remember, GDP we have C+I+NX. Well, any of these three, a change in investment, government spending, or net exports, it's going to have a multiplier effect on consumption. Okay? That's how this multiplier effect works. It affects consumption in multiples. Most of the time when you talk about the multiplier effect, it's dealing with either an increase in investment spending or an increase in government spending, like we're going to discuss here. So let's go ahead and kind of play it out. Let's see how it works. First, the government is going to increase their spending, which in turn increases the income of households. How does that happen? Well, the government say they start a new construction project. They decide to refurbish the highways and bridges of the country. Well, they're going to need to hire people, right? They're going to hire construction workers to fix the highways and that's more income going to households, right? They're creating jobs that's increasing income. So when these in these households have increased income, well, guess what? It's going to lead to higher household consumption. When they're making more money, they're going to spend a little more on consumption. And you can refer to the marginal propensity to consume. We talk about that in another video. That's the idea for every more income. When you have more income, you're going to save some and spend some. Consume more, I'll say consume some, save some. So the marginal propensity to consume deals with how much of that extra income goes towards consumption, okay? So, after, that increased consumption, well, that increased consumption is going to create another wave of consumption and there's going to be even more consumption based on that additional consumption. So more and more consumption and it's going to keep going based on that marginal propensity to consume. So let's imagine this example here. Government land has increased government spending by $5,000,000,000 So this initial $5,000,000,000 well, it's going to increase consumer spending. So let's imagine that those $5,000,000,000 that the government spent was all earned by households, okay? And let's say that households have a marginal propensity to consume of 0.75. So that means for every dollar that they earn, they're going to spend $0.75 of that dollar, okay? So let's get out of calculator and let's make this assumption right here. So, let's say the marginal propensity to consume is 75, that means this $5,000,000,000 of extra spending, 75% of it is going to be spent in the second round right here. So that means of the $5,000,000,000 the government spent, well, households earned $5,000,000,000 And then those households went out and spent $3,750,000,000 because of that. They saved the other portion of it, but they spent $3,750,000,000 and that $3,750,000,000 that was spent, well, it was earned by somebody and they're going to spend 75% of it. Right? So you can imagine that this 3.75 is now going to go through another round of multiplier effect here. And it's about $2,800,000,000 in the next round. So times 0.75 again is about $2,100,000,000 in the next round, and this keeps happening. Notice it keeps getting smaller, But this all in sum leads to a lot more, spending than just the initial $5,000,000,000 dollars right? There was initially $5,000,000,000 spent by the government, but it led to this chain reaction of extra spending based on people earning money and spending it and earning money and spending it, right? So this initial boost in spending has this multiplier effect. So how does this affect aggregate demand? Well, remember here, I'm going to move this over here. So right here, we had a chain government purchases increasing, and then consumption increasing, consumption increasing, consumption increasing, right? These are all parts of our GDP equation, parts of our aggregate demand. So as this happens, what we see on our aggregate demand graph is remember, this is price level and this is GDP over here. So if we were initially, at this point, well, we would first have one shift to the right from the government spending. So we'll say, from g, right? That first initial spending and then it's going to boost again, maybe a little smaller boost. And this will be from the first round of consumption and then another boost, maybe even smaller. And this is c2. Right? It keeps boosting to the right based on this additional spending. Right? So the multiplier effect really tells us that we don't just get this one boost from government purchases. There's multiple boosts going on here, right? It's not just the one boost to the aggregate demand. There's additional shifts that happen from this multiplier effect. So when it all rounds out, what actually happens with the multiplayer effect? Well, this is our equation right here. Remember that multiplier was all based on that marginal propensity to consume. When the consumers when the households got this extra money based on the government spending, well, they didn't spend all of it. So depending on how much of it they're willing to spend is how big the multiplier is going to be. You can imagine the more that the households are willing to spend, there's going to be a bigger multiplier effect because there's more and more spending going on. So this right here is how we calculate our multiplier. 1/1−MPC is the multiplier. Okay? So sometimes on a test, they'll just ask you what is the multiplier in this situation? And for our situation, we'd go 1/0.25 which is 4. So in our case, the multiplier was 4, meaning the initial spending of the government the initial spending, the government spent 5. Well, the total change in GDP would be 5 times 4, right? Our multiplier right there, which is 20. So when the marginal propensity to consume that MPC is 0.75, Well, an initial change of spending of 5 by the government actually affects the GDP by an increase of 20, Okay? So that's quite a big increase. So you can see that fiscal policy can have a multiplier effect in the sense that maybe just by increasing spending a little, there can be a great change in the economy. Okay? So there we go. That's the multiplier effect. Be familiar with this equation, 1/1−MPC. They love to test on that. Alright? Let's go ahead and move on to the next video.
- 1. Introduction to Macroeconomics1h 57m
- 2. Introductory Economic Models59m
- 3. Supply and Demand3h 43m
- Introduction to Supply and Demand10m
- The Basics of Demand7m
- Individual Demand and Market Demand6m
- Shifting Demand44m
- The Basics of Supply3m
- Individual Supply and Market Supply6m
- Shifting Supply28m
- Big Daddy Shift Summary8m
- Supply and Demand Together: Equilibrium, Shortage, and Surplus10m
- Supply and Demand Together: One-sided Shifts22m
- Supply and Demand Together: Both Shift34m
- Supply and Demand: Quantitative Analysis40m
- 4. Elasticity2h 26m
- Percentage Change and Price Elasticity of Demand19m
- Elasticity and the Midpoint Method20m
- Price Elasticity of Demand on a Graph11m
- Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand6m
- Total Revenue Test13m
- Total Revenue Along a Linear Demand Curve14m
- Income Elasticity of Demand23m
- Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand11m
- Price Elasticity of Supply12m
- Price Elasticity of Supply on a Graph3m
- Elasticity Summary9m
- 5. Consumer and Producer Surplus; Price Ceilings and Price Floors3h 40m
- Consumer Surplus and WIllingness to Pay33m
- Producer Surplus and Willingness to Sell26m
- Economic Surplus and Efficiency18m
- Quantitative Analysis of Consumer and Producer Surplus at Equilibrium28m
- Price Ceilings, Price Floors, and Black Markets38m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Floors: Finding Points20m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Floors: Finding Areas54m
- 6. Introduction to Taxes1h 25m
- 7. Externalities1h 3m
- 8. The Types of Goods1h 13m
- 9. International Trade1h 16m
- 10. Introducing Economic Concepts49m
- Introducing Concepts - Business Cycle7m
- Introducing Concepts - Nominal GDP and Real GDP12m
- Introducing Concepts - Unemployment and Inflation3m
- Introducing Concepts - Economic Growth6m
- Introducing Concepts - Savings and Investment5m
- Introducing Concepts - Trade Deficit and Surplus6m
- Introducing Concepts - Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy7m
- 11. Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and Consumer Price Index (CPI)1h 37m
- Calculating GDP11m
- Detailed Explanation of GDP Components9m
- Value Added Method for Measuring GDP1m
- Nominal GDP and Real GDP22m
- Shortcomings of GDP8m
- Calculating GDP Using the Income Approach10m
- Other Measures of Total Production and Total Income5m
- Consumer Price Index (CPI)13m
- Using CPI to Adjust for Inflation7m
- Problems with the Consumer Price Index (CPI)6m
- 12. Unemployment and Inflation1h 22m
- Labor Force and Unemployment9m
- Types of Unemployment12m
- Labor Unions and Collective Bargaining6m
- Unemployment: Minimum Wage Laws and Efficiency Wages7m
- Unemployment Trends7m
- Nominal Interest, Real Interest, and the Fisher Equation10m
- Nominal Income and Real Income12m
- Who is Affected by Inflation?5m
- Demand-Pull and Cost-Push Inflation6m
- Costs of Inflation: Shoe-leather Costs and Menu Costs4m
- 13. Productivity and Economic Growth1h 17m
- 14. The Financial System1h 37m
- 15. Income and Consumption52m
- 16. Deriving the Aggregate Expenditures Model1h 22m
- 17. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis1h 18m
- 18. The Monetary System1h 1m
- The Functions of Money; The Kinds of Money8m
- Defining the Money Supply: M1 and M24m
- Required Reserves and the Deposit Multiplier8m
- Introduction to the Federal Reserve8m
- The Federal Reserve and the Money Supply11m
- History of the US Banking System9m
- The Financial Crisis of 2007-2009 (The Great Recession)10m
- 19. Monetary Policy1h 32m
- 20. Fiscal Policy1h 0m
- 21. Revisiting Inflation, Unemployment, and Policy46m
- 22. Balance of Payments30m
- 23. Exchange Rates1h 16m
- Exchange Rates: Introduction14m
- Exchange Rates: Nominal and Real13m
- Exchange Rates: Equilibrium6m
- Exchange Rates: Shifts in Supply and Demand11m
- Exchange Rates and Net Exports6m
- Exchange Rates: Fixed, Flexible, and Managed Float5m
- Exchange Rates: Purchasing Power Parity7m
- The Gold Standard4m
- The Bretton Woods System6m
- 24. Macroeconomic Schools of Thought40m
- 25. Dynamic AD/AS Model35m
- 26. Special Topics11m
Government Purchases and the Multiplier Effect: Study with Video Lessons, Practice Problems & Examples
The multiplier effect illustrates how an initial change in government spending can lead to a larger overall increase in GDP. For instance, if the government spends $5 billion and households have a marginal propensity to consume (MPC) of 0.75, the total change in GDP can be calculated using the equation , resulting in a multiplier of 4. Thus, the total GDP increase would be $20 billion, demonstrating the significant impact of fiscal policy on aggregate demand.
Government Purchases GDP Multiplier
Video transcript
Here’s what students ask on this topic:
What is the multiplier effect in macroeconomics?
The multiplier effect in macroeconomics refers to the phenomenon where an initial change in spending (such as government spending) leads to a larger overall increase in GDP. This occurs because the initial spending creates income for households, which then spend a portion of this income, creating further income and spending in subsequent rounds. The size of the multiplier effect depends on the marginal propensity to consume (MPC). The formula to calculate the multiplier is . For example, if the MPC is 0.75, the multiplier is 4, meaning an initial $5 billion increase in spending could ultimately increase GDP by $20 billion.
How does government spending affect aggregate demand?
Government spending affects aggregate demand by directly increasing the total amount of spending in the economy. When the government spends money, for example on infrastructure projects, it creates jobs and income for households. These households then spend a portion of their increased income, further boosting consumption. This chain reaction, known as the multiplier effect, leads to multiple rounds of increased spending, shifting the aggregate demand curve to the right. The overall impact on aggregate demand depends on the size of the multiplier, which is determined by the marginal propensity to consume (MPC).
How do you calculate the multiplier in macroeconomics?
The multiplier in macroeconomics is calculated using the formula , where MPC stands for the marginal propensity to consume. This formula shows how much total GDP will change in response to an initial change in spending. For example, if the MPC is 0.75, the multiplier is = 4. This means that an initial $1 billion increase in government spending would ultimately increase GDP by $4 billion.
What is the relationship between the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) and the multiplier effect?
The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is directly related to the multiplier effect. The MPC measures the proportion of additional income that households will spend rather than save. The higher the MPC, the larger the multiplier effect, because more of each dollar of income is spent, leading to more rounds of spending. The multiplier is calculated using the formula . For example, if the MPC is 0.75, the multiplier is 4, meaning an initial increase in spending will have a fourfold impact on GDP.
Can the multiplier effect work in reverse with a decrease in government spending?
Yes, the multiplier effect can work in reverse with a decrease in government spending. When the government reduces its spending, it leads to a decrease in income for households, which then spend less. This reduction in spending causes further decreases in income and spending in subsequent rounds, leading to a larger overall decrease in GDP. The size of the negative multiplier effect also depends on the marginal propensity to consume (MPC). For example, if the MPC is 0.75, a $1 billion decrease in government spending could ultimately reduce GDP by $4 billion.