So let's see the derivation behind the multiplier equation that we use. We're going to use a little algebra here to find out how we came up with this one over one minus MPC for our multiplier. Okay? So what we're going to do is we're going to use a simplified model of aggregate expenditures, to calculate one over 1 minus MPC. Okay? So remember that this multiplier, it tells us that it signifies the multiple increase in GDP based on an initial increase in spending. So if we spend a little bit more on investment, well, that's going to have a multiple effect on the level of GDP in the economy. Okay? So let's start with the private closed economy where there's no government and no international trade just to make this equation look a little simpler, but it stands just the same when we add those in, okay? So, in a private closed economy, our aggregate expenditures are just consumption and investment, right? There's no government and no international trade. So we've just got C+ I for our aggregate expenditures. So we can expand our c for what we've been talking about consumption as the consumption function so far. There's the autonomous level of consumption as we say. There's that amount that's going to be there no matter what, right? If there was no income in the economy, no production, well, there would still be some consumption. We still have to eat. We still need shelter and clothes, right? So there would still be some consumption. But as we increase our disposable income, well, we're going to be increasing consumption based on that marginal propensity to consume, right? So there we go. That's our consumption function. All we did was expand our C+ I equation to have the consumption function plus I there. Okay? So since there are no taxes or government transfers in this model, well then, all of the income that earned that's earned is disposable income, right? There are no taxes. Right? There are no taxes, so every income that's earned is going to be, part of our disposable income. So we could just say that our aggregate expenditures equal a+mpc∙y+i. Okay? So all income is disposable. Income, we're not going to differentiate between the 2. And when we're in equilibrium, well, remember in equilibrium, our aggregate expenditures equal our GDP. So for GDP, we're going to use the term y for GDP. So, remember, this is GDP right here. Right? All the income that's earned, all the everything that's produced is earned by somebody and all of that is going to be involved in this consumption function. So we can say that our aggregate expenditures are equal to GDP which is equal to Y. So Y equals A+MPC∙Y+I. All we did was, substitute a e. Our aggregate expenditures, we just put in GDP for that because they're the same at equilibrium. MPC times Y plus investment. Okay? So what we're going to do is we're going to rearrange this formula to solve for GDP. We're going to rearrange the formula to solve for GDP and, all that takes is moving some of these factors around. So let's go ahead and move the MPC y to put the GDPs on the same side of the equation, And let's continue here. So we're going to have y-MPC∙y=a+i. Right? y-MPC∙y=a+i. Now this next step takes a little bit of algebra, but it should, it's just one little trick that we learned in algebra. When we have Y - MPC times y, we can factor out the Y. So we could have Y∙(1-MPC) And you can double check that, right? If we were to factor this back in, if we were to multiply it back in like this, we would have y✕1 is y minus MPC times y. Right? So all we did was we factored out the y from the equation which left us with 1-MPC. So Y∙(1-MPC)=a+i. Alright. So we're almost done. We just need to get the y by itself by dividing both sides by 1 minus MPC. So this will go away and we're left with y=a+mpc. Now I want to do one more thing to separate this out. I want to say y equals so I want to say 11-MPC. We can do this. We're going to separate the denominator from the numerator times a+i. Okay. So what does this tell us? Notice what this first bit here is. That's our multiplier. Right? So what it tells us is that if there's any increase over here, there's an increase in a+i in either a or I over there, and let me make it clear that these are i's right here. Those are all a+i, the investment. So if there's any increase, say, in investment, well, there's going to be a multiple effect on GDP. Right? GDP is going to be increased by not only the investment amount, but times the multiplier. Right? 11-MPC. So any increase from a change in the base amount of consumption or the amount of investment or say government purchases or net exports in an open economy, well, it'll result in a one over one minus MPC increase in equilibrium GDP. So that's the multiplier effect. That's how we derive that multiplier is that any increase in those constants are going to increase our GDP in a multiple amount and that is the multiplier there. That's the big thing about the multiplier is that by increasing the constant, we're multiplying the amount of GDP. Okay? So that has great effects in the economy when we're trying to boost GDP in the economy maybe during a recession. Well, if we boost our investment spending, it's going to have this multiple effect on our GDP. Okay? So that's about it. Nothing like I wouldn't expect if you don't understand this completely, I wouldn't expect the professor to like ask you to derive the multiplier, right? But some of them like to talk about it and maybe just have you understand on that level of how the investment increase will affect our GDP, okay? So that's about it here. Let's go ahead and move on to the next.
- 1. Introduction to Macroeconomics1h 57m
- 2. Introductory Economic Models59m
- 3. Supply and Demand3h 43m
- Introduction to Supply and Demand10m
- The Basics of Demand7m
- Individual Demand and Market Demand6m
- Shifting Demand44m
- The Basics of Supply3m
- Individual Supply and Market Supply6m
- Shifting Supply28m
- Big Daddy Shift Summary8m
- Supply and Demand Together: Equilibrium, Shortage, and Surplus10m
- Supply and Demand Together: One-sided Shifts22m
- Supply and Demand Together: Both Shift34m
- Supply and Demand: Quantitative Analysis40m
- 4. Elasticity2h 26m
- Percentage Change and Price Elasticity of Demand19m
- Elasticity and the Midpoint Method20m
- Price Elasticity of Demand on a Graph11m
- Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand6m
- Total Revenue Test13m
- Total Revenue Along a Linear Demand Curve14m
- Income Elasticity of Demand23m
- Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand11m
- Price Elasticity of Supply12m
- Price Elasticity of Supply on a Graph3m
- Elasticity Summary9m
- 5. Consumer and Producer Surplus; Price Ceilings and Price Floors3h 40m
- Consumer Surplus and WIllingness to Pay33m
- Producer Surplus and Willingness to Sell26m
- Economic Surplus and Efficiency18m
- Quantitative Analysis of Consumer and Producer Surplus at Equilibrium28m
- Price Ceilings, Price Floors, and Black Markets38m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Floors: Finding Points20m
- Quantitative Analysis of Price Ceilings and Floors: Finding Areas54m
- 6. Introduction to Taxes1h 25m
- 7. Externalities1h 3m
- 8. The Types of Goods1h 13m
- 9. International Trade1h 16m
- 10. Introducing Economic Concepts49m
- Introducing Concepts - Business Cycle7m
- Introducing Concepts - Nominal GDP and Real GDP12m
- Introducing Concepts - Unemployment and Inflation3m
- Introducing Concepts - Economic Growth6m
- Introducing Concepts - Savings and Investment5m
- Introducing Concepts - Trade Deficit and Surplus6m
- Introducing Concepts - Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy7m
- 11. Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and Consumer Price Index (CPI)1h 37m
- Calculating GDP11m
- Detailed Explanation of GDP Components9m
- Value Added Method for Measuring GDP1m
- Nominal GDP and Real GDP22m
- Shortcomings of GDP8m
- Calculating GDP Using the Income Approach10m
- Other Measures of Total Production and Total Income5m
- Consumer Price Index (CPI)13m
- Using CPI to Adjust for Inflation7m
- Problems with the Consumer Price Index (CPI)6m
- 12. Unemployment and Inflation1h 22m
- Labor Force and Unemployment9m
- Types of Unemployment12m
- Labor Unions and Collective Bargaining6m
- Unemployment: Minimum Wage Laws and Efficiency Wages7m
- Unemployment Trends7m
- Nominal Interest, Real Interest, and the Fisher Equation10m
- Nominal Income and Real Income12m
- Who is Affected by Inflation?5m
- Demand-Pull and Cost-Push Inflation6m
- Costs of Inflation: Shoe-leather Costs and Menu Costs4m
- 13. Productivity and Economic Growth1h 17m
- 14. The Financial System1h 37m
- 15. Income and Consumption52m
- 16. Deriving the Aggregate Expenditures Model1h 22m
- 17. Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Analysis1h 18m
- 18. The Monetary System1h 1m
- The Functions of Money; The Kinds of Money8m
- Defining the Money Supply: M1 and M24m
- Required Reserves and the Deposit Multiplier8m
- Introduction to the Federal Reserve8m
- The Federal Reserve and the Money Supply11m
- History of the US Banking System9m
- The Financial Crisis of 2007-2009 (The Great Recession)10m
- 19. Monetary Policy1h 32m
- 20. Fiscal Policy1h 0m
- 21. Revisiting Inflation, Unemployment, and Policy46m
- 22. Balance of Payments30m
- 23. Exchange Rates1h 16m
- Exchange Rates: Introduction14m
- Exchange Rates: Nominal and Real13m
- Exchange Rates: Equilibrium6m
- Exchange Rates: Shifts in Supply and Demand11m
- Exchange Rates and Net Exports6m
- Exchange Rates: Fixed, Flexible, and Managed Float5m
- Exchange Rates: Purchasing Power Parity7m
- The Gold Standard4m
- The Bretton Woods System6m
- 24. Macroeconomic Schools of Thought40m
- 25. Dynamic AD/AS Model35m
- 26. Special Topics11m
Deriving the Multiplier Algebraically - Online Tutor, Practice Problems & Exam Prep
The multiplier effect illustrates how an initial increase in spending, such as investment, leads to a greater overall increase in GDP. In a private closed economy, aggregate expenditures consist of consumption (C) and investment (I). The equation for GDP (Y) can be derived as Y=1-MPC(A+I), where MPC is the marginal propensity to consume. This demonstrates that any increase in consumption or investment will multiply the effect on GDP, crucial for economic stabilization during downturns.
Deriving the Multiplier Algebraically
Video transcript
Here’s what students ask on this topic:
What is the formula for the multiplier in macroeconomics?
The formula for the multiplier in macroeconomics is derived as follows: In a private closed economy, aggregate expenditures (AE) consist of consumption (C) and investment (I). The consumption function can be expanded to include autonomous consumption (A) and the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) times income (Y). Thus, AE = A + MPC * Y + I. At equilibrium, AE equals GDP (Y), so Y = A + MPC * Y + I. Rearranging this equation to solve for Y, we get Y = (A + I) / (1 - MPC). The multiplier (k) is therefore 1 / (1 - MPC).
How does the multiplier effect impact GDP?
The multiplier effect impacts GDP by amplifying the initial increase in spending. For example, if there is an increase in investment (I), this initial spending leads to increased income and consumption, which further increases GDP. The formula Y = (A + I) / (1 - MPC) shows that any increase in autonomous consumption (A) or investment (I) will result in a multiplied increase in GDP. This is crucial for economic stabilization, especially during downturns, as it shows how government spending or investment can significantly boost overall economic activity.
What is the significance of the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) in the multiplier formula?
The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is a key component in the multiplier formula. It represents the fraction of additional income that households spend on consumption. The multiplier is calculated as 1 / (1 - MPC), indicating that a higher MPC leads to a larger multiplier. This means that when households spend a greater portion of their additional income, the initial increase in spending has a more significant impact on GDP. Understanding MPC helps policymakers predict the effectiveness of fiscal policies aimed at stimulating economic growth.
How do you derive the multiplier algebraically?
To derive the multiplier algebraically, start with the aggregate expenditures (AE) in a private closed economy: AE = C + I. Expand the consumption function to include autonomous consumption (A) and the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) times income (Y): AE = A + MPC * Y + I. At equilibrium, AE equals GDP (Y), so Y = A + MPC * Y + I. Rearrange to solve for Y: Y - MPC * Y = A + I. Factor out Y: Y * (1 - MPC) = A + I. Finally, solve for Y: Y = (A + I) / (1 - MPC). The multiplier (k) is thus 1 / (1 - MPC).
Why is the multiplier important in macroeconomics?
The multiplier is important in macroeconomics because it quantifies the impact of an initial change in spending on the overall economy. It shows how an increase in autonomous spending, such as investment or government expenditure, can lead to a larger increase in GDP. This concept is crucial for understanding how fiscal policies can be used to stabilize the economy, especially during recessions. By knowing the multiplier, policymakers can estimate the potential effects of their actions on economic output and make informed decisions to promote growth and stability.